Ladies and Gentlemen, Dear Friends,
We began yesterday to work out some basic
outlines from the course by Rudolf Steiner and I took the liberty of pointing
out that the two main pillars that carry the whole course consist of the two
ways of creating value, two ways that work can be done, namely the
transubstantiating and the incarnating labor, and that by means of their
cooperation and intersection prices arise and just price should be formed. For
reasons of methodology, I have distinguished fairly sharply between these two
branches of labor in order to define these two modes of determining the social
organic process as distinctly as possible. Naturally, it is apparent that none
of these two ways and means of labor output and surplus value creation exist in
the economic reality purely by themselves, but that both of them are always
interconnected, so that we can only speak of a predominance of the one or the
other. We have already seen when looking at the means of production that these
two streams intertwine in a special way in these means of production.
If
we look at the origin of the means of
production, there is a predominance of incarnating labor involved. But that is
not the only thing to be considered, for also the nature products and the
fabrication of semi-finished products must be taken into consideration;
predominant, however, is the incarnating labor, because it takes a lot of
spiritual, mental work to make a machine.
In
the use of the means of production,
transubstantiating labor prevails, because the latter goes into the making of
consumer goods. But there the organizing labor [management] must also play a
role. So, with regard to the means of production, we clearly see how both ways
of creating surplus value and performing work are intertwined.
We
finished yesterday by looking at the social organic trinity of the concepts:
paying – lending – giving. We can begin by considering the concept of giving.
The making of gifts is distinguished for their part again in the light of the
immanent threefold components that form the basis of economic life: one can
give to the sphere of purchase money by pressing a 10 dollar bill into the hand
of a hungry person, but actually one gives in this case also to the free
spiritual, cultural life. For when the hungry person can keep his physical
organism in order, one offers him the possibility of also keeping his spirit,
his mind in order. Donating is always a question of giving to the free
spiritual life. But one can obviously give in a more direct way to the
spiritual sphere, to especially productive individuals or centers of learning,
not only to schools for children, but to free universities that constitute the
centers of the free spiritual life – and everyone actually forms such a free
university around himself.
When
one makes a gift with a view to furthering the rights sphere so that
associative or advisory bodies can be formed, it is also a donation to the free
spiritual life, for it is a matter thereby of endowing the spiritual activity
that formulates and constitutes rights.
A
very special type of donation takes place when capital resources in the form of
factories are not handed over by right of heredity, but on the basis of
associatively formed judgments to the most capable persons. This is also a
basic task of the associations: transferring the means of production, motivated
by judgments formed out of a true community spirit, to the most capable people,
whereby not the mechanism casts the deciding vote, but the creative potential
that a person brings to the fore. Thereby it is not a question of handing over
the ownership of the factories, for these belong in the sense of social
organics to the general public. No, the firms and factories are put at the
disposal of those individuals that, on the basis of decisions made by the
associations, are deemed to be the best suited for managing the task at hand.
But these decisions can naturally only come about in the right way and in the
right spirit, if they are based on and carried by true knowledge of the human
being and of the world.
In
this context, I would like to quote yet another time from the course. With the
gifts that we just spoke about, it is a matter of caring for the free spiritual
life (culture), and when this declines - as is visible for example in our time
– it must be clear that this is not due to a lack of human capabilities; these
lie within the spiritual nature of the human being and are being taken care of
by the spiritual world. But when these potentials are not being developed, it
is because too little is being donated to the spiritual life and because too
little knowledge concerning this exists; that is why the decisions to make
gifts are not taken (p. 82): “These associations will find that when spiritual
life declines, too little is being given freely; they will grasp the
connection. They see the connection between too little giving and too little
free spiritual work.” Their task is then to let more capital flow in the
direction of gift possibilities.
When
we look closer at this trinity of the concepts paying – lending – giving, we
see immediately that nothing could be paid for or bought, if there was no
transubstantiating creation of value: NLV. Lending is that process of directing
personal credit on the basis of associative capital flow decisions and
judgments to capable people, so that the other creation of surplus value, the
incarnating one, can arise when the spirit or mind is applied to labor. These
processes work into each other and with each other. Lending reduces the cost of
purchasing, for transubstantiating labor becomes cheaper to the extent that
more incarnating labor is applied to it. That causes an increase in the value
of products. The more value a product has, the cheaper it is.
Loan
money makes purchase money valuable, because it reduces the costs of
commodities. Through purchasing, on the other hand, more capital arises, that
can be used for personal credit. But now it must be taken care of that the
overflowing capital does not accumulate and pile up on the (unimproved) land in
collateral credit. Therefore, the profit made from the sale must be transferred
into the gift sphere, fructifying the free spiritual life and offering new
possibilities for making personal credit available to capable personalities.
Lending, on the other hand, i.e. giving personal credit to set up means of
production, generates surplus capital again, that also needs to be transferred
to the gift sphere. But making gifts, for its part, reacts again on the sphere
of purchase money, because it has the indirect effect via personal credit of
making commodities cheaper and increasing the value of purchase money. In that
way, the three spheres are intertwined; that is how they function together. It
is important to always ask oneself: how does the trinity of concepts work
together and into one another, and how is this then expressed in the forming of
price?
The
forming of the just price has been occupying us, and what actually underlies
and must underlie every view on social organics. Now there are in the economic
life of today a number of price-falsifying influences. We cannot take the time
to make a list of all these factors; we can only deal with the most important
ones. Wages are considered to be the price for the work that is done. Today
practically everyone is still convinced that the worker sells his work to the
entrepreneur and that the entrepreneur pays the worker for his work. The
economic confusion and the social struggles of our time actually all revolve
around this question of wages, even when it is masked by saying that it
revolves around the human dignity of the work.
As
soon as somebody demands something in exchange for his work output, he demands
a wage, and if he is willing and able to accept something in return for his
labor as demanded, he is practicing self-sufficiency. Yet, it is an illusion to
believe that the work in the factories is paid for and, as a matter of fact,
could even be paid for. To be sure, in the present social conflicts of the
working world this illusion has been turned into a reality, but it is in
reality an illusion. For work cannot be bought, it is not an object, a
commodity that can be consumed; work is rather something that is connected with
the spiritual nature of the human being. We cannot move a finger without a
spiritual impulse. The transubstantiating labor also has its origins in an
incarnation process, in bringing spiritual forces in and out. Work cannot be
bought. The entrepreneur does not buy the work from the worker, but the product
that the worker makes.
Here
we are faced again with the central price problem: What is the right relation between
V1 and V2, of
transubstantiation value and incarnation value? The worker works primarily on
the transubstantiating side, while the entrepreneur – and especially so as
trader, which he also is – stands on the incarnating side. In the sale of
transubstantiation products in compensation for incarnation products, we have
again a meeting of V1 and V2, and the right balance between the two values must be
expressed in a right primary price for the transubstantiation product. Wages do
not exist; there is only a primary price for the transubstantiation product.
This is a just price when it is properly weighed in relation to incarnating
labor that causes an increase in the value of the transubstantiation product by
reducing its cost. Hence the question is: how can the increase of value of the
transubstantiation product be expressed in its primary price, an increase in
value that occurs by its being put on the market by the entrepreneur and
thereby reduced in cost.
V1 and V2 meet again
at the point where the entrepreneur as trader buys the primary products. This
draws our attention again to that most important question of price formation.
Another quote (p. 90): “This therefore is the most important question in
relation to price formation: How can we harmonize the tension that exists in
the creation of prices between the evaluation of goods arising from the free
will of human beings and that of goods in the production of which nature has a
hand?” Again, V1
and V2 are meeting head on.
In trying to understand the problem of price formation, it
can be helpful to bring to mind that we have so far looked at two processes in
the social organism flowing in opposite directions. The first one was called
the transubstantiating current flowing in the direction of V1 with nature as its source. The second one
flows in the opposite direction, because it does not reside in nature; it has
its source in the spiritual life and goes in the direction of the value
creation V2.
The V1 current
begins in nature that is transformed by human labor, and then the process of
creating value already moves into the forming of V2 by virtue of the fact that the human mind is
applied to labor. At this moment, the current passes over into the
counter-current, which is mainly expressed by the transubstantiation products
being only enhanced to the degree that they become means of production. When
these means of production are again put to work as such, they are called industrial capital.
V1 Spirit (Mind)
Labor (Work) ¯
Nature V2
Transubstantiation Incarnation
This is the capital, the value
creating potential that the entrepreneur puts at the disposal of the workers
occupied in the transubstantiation current. This incarnation stream thereby
passes over into the transubstantiation stream; consumer products are made that
are directly put on the market and consumed in a natural process. This constant
counter-current of two streams that are transformed into each other, their
opposition, constitutes the whole social organic process; and the equalization
of the two streams that arises from the cooperation and collusion of the
polarities is one of the most important social organic tasks.
This
will be the task of the associations, which they can fulfill by harmonizing the
creation of values, by balancing the parts that both streams play in the social
organic process through the corresponding control of capital, but also by
guiding and managing the workers. Just or true prices arise by controlling the
flow of capital in this whole stream in the right way.
Now the social-economic thinking of today is to a large
extent dominated by the old prejudice that true prices will come about by
themselves on the market and that nothing more needs to be done than to see to
it that there is a free play of supply and demand on the market. Within this
free play prices can and must be formed; this is the old view of Adam Smith,
which is still dominant in today’s social economic thinking.
Now
according to Rudolf Steiner, this generalization of Smith’s formula – price
formation through the interaction of supply and demand – is justified to a
certain, limited degree; it must however not be generalized, for it must be
understood that supply and demand exist everywhere in the social organic
process, and that one party is not only supplying and the other merely
demanding. When the producer brings his goods to the market, he is not only a
supplier; putting goods on the market is a demand for money, while the consumer
on the other hand makes a demand in buying goods, a demand for goods. Putting
goods on the market is demand for money, and buying goods is based on a supply
of money. This gives rise to the three famous formula’s which Rudolf Steiner
put forward in the World Economy Course (p. 100) and which, as you know,
caused a great deal of discussion.
One
of the reasons for the misunderstanding which, in my opinion, entered into
those discussions, is that the corresponding text by Rudolf Steiner on this
point is obviously partly wrong. But let us look at these equations and try to
understand them.
Rudolf
Steiner says namely: X – that is value formation and price formation – is a
function of three factors that are all equally justified, a function of supply,
demand and price: X = ƒ (s,d,p). But,
says Rudolf Steiner, this function for X is only the case in the sphere of the
trader, where it can thus be said: p = ƒ (s,d). The trader equation is
therefore essentially accurate, because in trade it is actually neither a
question of money or goods, but something midway in between money and goods.
Then consider: for the trader the goods that he offers are money, and the money
that he takes in, he transforms immediately into goods. He offers money-goods mg and takes in goods-money gm, so that we must change the price X
to money-goods. It comes about in the evaluation of a supply of money-goods or
goods-money meeting a demand for goods-money or money-goods.
Now
there is furthermore a producer and a
consumer equation. We have already seen:
When the producer puts his goods on the market, it is a demand for something.
For what? Money; I must there write index m; this demand is a function of
supply and price: dm = ƒ (s,p). With
consumers it is not a matter of demand for money, but supply of money. And that
is again a function of two factors, namely of price and demand: sm = ƒ (p,d).
The
question is: What is meant by supply and demand? With the producers equation it
is quite clear that the producer expresses a demand for money and that his
supply is one of goods. But what is this price p? Is that the goods price? Do
we write down pg? Does a supply of
goods not become a demand for money, in the background of which stands a demand
for goods? In that case, we would have the trader’s equation again. If you
write pg for that, you flatten it
out, and that cannot be right. And if you read the World Economy Course concerning this point carefully, you will
notice that also Rudolf Steiner indirectly said that it cannot be a matter of
the price of the goods, but a matter of the prices that the producer sets for
his products. These prices he sets and can set according to what can be
obtained within the social organic process.
Now
what is the possibility of determining and fetching this price dependent on? On
the value and price of money. It is obviously a question of the price of money,
for otherwise it reverts back to Smith’s formula. When the producer demands
money by offering his wares, he can only do this within the realm of the
obtainable prices. And these obtainable prices, which are expressed in money,
arise from the general possibilities within the social organic process and
these are precipitated in the price and value of money. It cannot be otherwise
in my opinion.
Now
we come to the consumer equation. The
consumer has money and offers it. This money supply is connected with the
interaction of two factors, namely price and supply. Price here obviously means
the price of the goods pg, and this
is set by the seller on the basis of demand. But demand for what? For money dm. The less he
demands money or the less the value of the money, the higher he sets the price
for his goods. And conversely, the higher the value of the money, the lower he
sets the price of his goods. Here we have to do with the interplay of the price
of goods and the demand for money. This is the answer to the supply of money by
the consumer. Only in this way, I believe, can these equations be interpreted.
pmg = ƒ(smg, dgm) Traders
equation
dm
= ƒ(sg, pm) Producers equation
sm
= ƒ(pg, dm) Consumers equation
If you examine this closely, you will
recognize that a different indexing of the factors always reverts back to
Smith’s one-sided formula, which is only valid for traders. I have advocated
this view now and then before to the amazement of my audience, which is perhaps
also the case here among some you, because I spoke of the price of money. But today in these times of inflation we live
daily with “the price of money”. And moreover, the concept “price of money”
appears in Rudolf Steiner’s course itself. I could quote you a whole list, but
I will give you only a few examples (p. 150):
“How does money itself influence the forming of price? For
money itself plays the chief part nowadays both in the ordinary purchase and
sale, and in the payment of wages, and in all the rest of economic life as
well. We must distinguish between that which eventually emerges as price in
terms of money, and that which constitutes the essential value of money in the
hand of one man or another.”
Or a little later that (p. 151):
“Money as such receives
its value by the free process of circulation.”
This is expressed in the price of money, in
the currency. Then (p. 153):
“Economically the
situation is that money itself, simply through the economic process, undergoes
change.”
Or once again (p. 158):
“In that case I would be
a bad economist if I used very young money. For young money, by virtue of its
youth, is the most valuable and accordingly the most expensive. Thus, if I need
the money for a shorter period, I shall provide myself with cheaper money.”
This we must speak about later.
The
concept price of money is no doubt mentioned here by Rudolf Steiner, as is
evidenced by the text; this is a philological issue, not a cognitive one. But
we can also understand it, for money becomes valuable and its price as well, in
the social organic process by virtue of its aging. We have reached the question
of the aging of money.
(Pause)
1. Short answer to a question:
Social organic control of capital is only sensible against
the background of a viable worldview of the nature of the human being and the
world. All social organic processes only serve to give human beings the chance
to experience themselves as spiritual beings living productively in a spiritual
world.
2. Short answer to a question:
Economic rationalization gives rise
to leisure time, which can enable individuals to partake in the social and cultural
activities of a free spiritual life. This spiritual life must be present within
society with initiative and productivity. But there is something else. If the
incarnating value only takes place towards a maximization of profits, we are
moving in a direction without social organic style. It is namely not only a
matter of maximization and so-called price reduction of products, if with that
is meant their human, spiritual value. Incarnating labor should not only be
looked at from the viewpoint of rationalization (efficiency), but from the
viewpoint of the enhancement of products in connection with the enhancement of
human needs. The rationalization of labor must be properly weighed against the
labor of enhancement. Thus, no
rationalization without human enhancement!
It
is very true that we require a stable value of money, but a balanced, not a
static one. So that one can say: currency devaluation only in connection with
synchronous currency revaluation. Money value may also decrease to the degree
that new money arises. This brings us to a very important concept of the social
economic course, the concept of old and
young money. Rudolf Steiner speaks about old and young money, because money
in the sense of social organics can be nothing else than an order for
(obtaining) values. Economic values are expressed for the most part in the
means of production in which the two values, the transubstantiating and the
incarnating ones, flow together. That is how money is covered – real financial
collateral can consist only of the useful means of production, useful in the
sense of true social organics, for those means of productions used for making
weapons of mass destruction are in this sense not useful and cannot create
financial security. Money can only be covered by useful means of production.
That is its real value. Not real, for example, is the value that is deposited
on fallow land in the form of collateral credit. Once it is understood that
money can only be covered by the useful means of productions, then it can also
be understood that money must age and die as well as be born. It must age to
the degree that the means of production are worn out. They can under certain
circumstances be devalued completely by one industrial process being replaced
by another that is not only more rational, but that has a greater value in
enhancing human needs. To that degree money ages, it becomes old; as the means
of production become old, money must get old and diminish in value. But when it
only ages, the social organic process cannot go on. The aging must go hand in
hand with money creation. There must be young money to the degree that there is
old money. That is how stability in the process can be achieved.
We
see that the value of money is on the one hand dependent on human capabilities.
By making new means of production, organizing takes place, spirit is applied
and products arise. (Process: money creation, money regeneration, renewal.) By
using these means of production, money too is worn out; it gets old,
depreciates and expires. Now a very interesting question comes up here. The old
money must be taken out of circulation by the associations. New money can only
be brought into circulation to the extent that goods are produced. If aging
money predominates, and therefore an inflationary tendency arises, the
circulation of money must be decreased, because an increase in the money
circulation decreased its value.
Naturally,
the more means of production are made, the more money can be brought into
circulation. In the light of the social organic process, currency depreciation
must be met with a decrease in the money circulation, the opposite of what
happens today.[1] Through
increasing and decreasing the value of money (regeneration and devaluation) the
associations can control the money flow by, for example, directing young money
to the loan sphere. Young money increases in value. It is spent on newly made
means of productions. It increases in value, if these means of production are
used in the sense of social organics, from a minimal value to the highest
maximum value possible. At that point, it should enter into the purchasing
sphere. It diminishes in value when the means of production become old and worn
out and need to be replaced. The money that has become old can under certain
circumstances be steered directly into the gift sphere, where it is only a
question of taking care of the daily needs of those spiritually productive;
they for their part contribute to the creation of young money in the future.[2]
Not a statistical stability of the money value is obtained in this way, but a
stabilization by balancing the aging process and regeneration of money, whereby
the aging corresponds to a decrease in the money circulation and the
regeneration to an increase.
There
is another formula given by Rudolf Steiner that is worthwhile considering. The
forming of the just price by balancing both value streams in the right way: V1, on the one
hand can also be expressed by N (Nature) times L (Labor) = V1. On the
other hand, we have seen that through the incarnating value V2, labor is
saved, i.e. negative labor. Now the
Course gives for the V2 formula: Spirit minus Labor. In my opinion, however, it should
be: Spirit times minus Labor V2 = S ´ (- L). In the Course it is not
printed in that way, but this is obviously an error. Labor is not subtracted
from the spirit, labor is saved and therefore it must read:
V2 = S ´ (- L)
Spirit times minus Labor
V1 = N ´ L Nature
times plus Labor
My reflections have led to this interpretation.
In this proper balancing act just price originates. It is based on the to and
fro of the process of steering transubstantiating and incarnating labor. The
two value currents intermingle; neither appears purely by itself.
I
would still like to point out a few other problems that seem especially topical
to me. One of them is the currency
problem. If it is understood that just price originates by balancing
“Nature times plus Labor” against “Spirit times minus Labor” in the right way,
if it is understood that the labor that would have to be expended for the
forming of V1 is saved by the forming of V2, then it
must be said that this conservation of labor expresses the value of this
incarnating labor. The incarnation worker would therefore have to get from the
transubstantiation side so much as a counter value as is saved by his output,
and this would have to correspond, if things go right, to what he needs to
cover his necessities in life in order to again produce the same output or an
equivalent.
We have heard, on the one hand, the formula
that the value of the transubstantiation labor saved is determined by the
incarnation worker having to receive for his costs of living that which is
necessary to produce the same output or an equivalent. If everything runs as it
should, then the necessities in life for the time that he requires in order to
produce his spiritual output corresponds with the amount of transubstantiation
labor saved by the incarnating labor. With that the following objection can be
met: A toddler making only a few strokes gets more than a hard-working painter.
We
come to a third, important point of view: All transubstantiating labor is made
possible by the available land, not only farmland, but also the natural
resources underground. What is available
for the individual within the transubstantiation sphere can be expressed by the
ratio of land area to population. Every single member of the earth’s population
would have in principle that much land area available as results from this
ratio. The increase in value of the earthly usability of the land is
proportional to the means of productions that are applied to this land area,
for the land itself has no value; otherwise we would get into the sphere of
collateral credit. The value of the land area is expressed by the totality of
the means of production capable of being put to use on it. Accordingly, the
currency factor is the ratio land to population, i.e. La : Po. That is the real
currency coefficient. We must thereby proceed from an average land area, not
from a desert, and must bring this average land area in relation to the
population and the means of production applied to, or used on this land. That
is the currency coefficient according to the facts of reality and that is what
matters here. Each member of the population would therefore have to receive so
much for his basic necessities for living as corresponds to the value of the
average land area allotted to him. The prices for calculating his basic needs
must be included in this factor. The prices may therefore not go beyond the
margin in value (German: Wertspanne) that is thereby expressed. In this
respect, we have a currency regulator. The time factor is expressed by the
working factor (German: Bearbeitungsfaktor). The value that arises in a certain
work time is available for the individual in his leisure time.
Now
among the many questions that all this raises there is an important one with
respect to the fundamental social law that contains the social organic
altruism, the social organic reciprocity. With a certain justification, but
only based on a misunderstanding, it could be objected here that one of the
most important, powerful incentives to
work, namely working for profit, would disappear if this law became valid.
It is said today and rightly so: People will no longer work, if there are no
more incentives. But then it is interpreted falsely in the way that only the
prospect of gain expressed in possessions, property etc. provide an incentive
for the human being and that this is simply human nature. I say that in a
modern, structured social organism profit remains as before the decisive
incentive, but in a modern metamorphosis. Then it will also be a matter of
profit, but profit as gain in
productivity. There must be as much productivity flowing in as possible,
and the desire for increasing productivity will continue to be the incentive.
Let me close with a final
observation. The social organic process
came to the fore as the interpenetration of V1 and V2, the transubstantiating and
incarnation values. This interpenetration leads always to a work of art, to the
highest art that there is, the social work of art, and the health and beauty of
this social work of art is expressed in the just price, in the right money
value. I would like to add two short points of views to that.
Social
organic transubstantiation requires a common conscious awareness that comes to
life in mutual acts of giving in the sense of the fundamental social law. This
law says: The gain in productivity is greater, the less I keep my productivity
for myself, and the more unrestrictedly I donate my productivity to the social
organism. Then, depending on its contents, something out of this great
collecting pot can be given back, always with respect to the La : Pop, the
currency coefficient. This requires a common consciousness, a consciousness of
mutual giving. In this realm there is a consciousness over and beyond what the
individual human being can encompass with his personal consciousness. Transubstantiating labor leads within the
consciousness of mutual giving to the forming of a common consciousness in the
sense of the Christmas Conference [3],
which points to the fundamental social factor of the future, to the forming of
a common consciousness that can absorb more than the sum total of the individual
conscious minds. An enhanced, higher consciousness content can become present
within the common consciousness of the transubstantiating labor; there a
super-terrestrial community life can be experienced. That is why the fundamental
social law is designated as the law of occultism:
A higher potential in super-terrestrial consciousness becomes present in the
mutual acts of giving. Every active in the field of transubstantiating labor
experiences himself within and through this common consciousness as its
representative. This is one of the great sources of labor and labor output
that at the same time expresses the human dignity of labor by virtue of living,
being active and working in the sphere of a common super-terrestrial consciousness.
That makes their work sensible and worthy of a human being.
The
other great working impulse is not connected with community consciousness, but
with the consciousness of freedom, the basis of which - as is shown by soul
observation - is the realization faculty of the human being.
The
human being realizes reality by constantly letting living concepts flow into
his percepts, which are individualized in this process. He does not receive a
ready-made reality; he has to first create it, he is a constant ‘realizer’.
Since he is not dependent on a finished reality, he is a free human being. This
realizing-consciousness is the source of all creativity, out of which all
creative activity flows forth. This experiencing of oneself in freedom and
realizing-consciousness is the other great working impulse. The community
consciousness in the sense of the fundamental social law through the
reciprocity of the acts of giving that lead to the representative consciousness
is a future consciousness, while the consciousness of freedom draws on the past
of the spiritual world, from which human beings bring forth their free creative
impulses and ever new driving forces. V1 and V2 unite, as you see, in the streaming together
of these two fundamental working impulses and incentives; they must stream
together in associative or advisory bodies, in which then a constantly renewing
and continuing formation of the rights sphere takes place, in which true
justice in the balancing of the two value poles, leads to Just Price.
The
working world economy and the social community will not be rescued by a world
computer [internet], but by a network of associations spread out over the whole
earth, a network in which community consciousness and consciousness of
productive and creative freedom can meet and confer in human beings, because
they have become capable of speech.
These then were some small samples
from the social organic Course.
[1] During inflation
the rate of the circulation of money increases. (Note by the publisher of the German
original edition).
[2] The words in the future were added to this
sentence by the German publisher.
[3] On the occasion of the so-called Christmas Conference during the turn of the year 1923/24, the Anthroposophical
Society was founded anew in Dornach (Switzerland). See Herbert Witzenmann, The Principles of the Anthroposophical
Society, working translation, Willehalm Institute, 6th ed.
Amsterdam, 2001.
Now rereading what I wrote at the turn of the century, two things strike me. Firstly how actual these views still are and secondly how nobody has bothered to leave any comment. Must mankind go through anothere terrible world war, before it is realized that it is the absence of social organics that drives us into whole sale slaugther and the destruction the true image of man and the sort social body he needs to live in and thrive?
ReplyDelete